翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Matching Green
・ Matching Head and Feet
・ Matching hypothesis
・ Matching Jack
・ Matching law
・ Matching Mole
・ Matching Mole (album)
・ Matching Mole's Little Red Record
・ Matching pennies
・ Matching person and technology model
・ Matching polynomial
・ Matching preclusion
・ Matching principle
・ Matching pursuit
・ Matching Sweaters
Matching theory (economics)
・ Matching Tye
・ Matching, Essex
・ Matchlee Mountain
・ Matchless
・ Matchless (disambiguation)
・ Matchless (film)
・ Matchless (pleasure yacht)
・ Matchless Amplifiers
・ Matchless G12
・ Matchless G3/L
・ Matchless G50
・ Matchless G80
・ Matchless G9
・ Matchless Magazine


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Matching theory (economics) : ウィキペディア英語版
Matching theory (economics)

In economics, matching theory, also known as search and matching theory, is a mathematical framework attempting to describe the formation of mutually beneficial relationships over time.
Matching theory has been especially influential in labor economics, where it has been used to describe the formation of new jobs, as well as to describe other human relationships like marriage. Matching theory evolved from an earlier framework called 'search theory'. Where search theory studies the microeconomic decision of an individual searcher, matching theory studies the macroeconomic outcome when one or more types of searchers interact. It offers a way of modeling markets in which frictions prevent instantaneous adjustment of the level of economic activity. Among other applications, it has been used as a framework for studying frictional unemployment.
One of the founders of matching theory is Dale T. Mortensen of Northwestern University. A textbook treatment of the matching approach to labor markets is Christopher A. Pissarides' book ''Equilibrium Unemployment Theory''. Mortensen and Pissarides, together with Peter A. Diamond, were awarded the 2010 Nobel Prize in Economics for 'fundamental contributions to search and matching theory'.〔(Economic Prize Committee of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, 'Scientific Background', page 2. )〕 The 2012 Economic Prize Committee of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences was awarded to Alvin E. Roth and Lloyd Shapley for their work on matching theory.〔http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/2012/〕
==The matching function==
A matching function is a mathematical relationship that describes the formation of new relationships (also called 'matches') from unmatched agents of the appropriate types. For example, in the context of job formation, matching functions are sometimes assumed to have the following 'Cobb–Douglas' form:
:m_t \; = \; M(u_t,v_t) \; = \; \mu u_t^a v_t^b
where \,\mu\,, \,a\,, and \,b\, are positive constants.
In this equation, \,u_t\, represents the number of unemployed job seekers in the economy at a given time \,t\,, and \,v_t\, is the number of vacant jobs firms are trying to fill. The number of new relationships (matches) created (per unit of time) is given by \,m_t\,.
A matching function is in general analogous to a production function. But whereas a production function usually represents the production of goods and services from inputs like labor and capital, a matching function represents the formation of new relationships from the pools of available unmatched individuals. Estimates of the labor market matching function suggest that it has constant returns to scale, that is, a+b\approx 1.
If the fraction of jobs that separate (due to firing, quits, and so forth) from one period to the next is \,\delta\,,
then to calculate the change in employment from one period to the next we must add the formation of new matches and subtract off the separation of old matches. A period may be treated as a week, a month, a quarter, or some other convenient period of time, depending on the data under consideration. (For simplicity, we are ignoring the entry of new workers into the labor force, and death or retirement of old workers, but these issues can be accounted for as well.) Suppose we write the number of workers employed in period \,t\, as \,n_t=L_t-u_t\,, where \,L_t\, is the labor force in period \,t\,. Then given the matching function described above, the dynamics of employment over time would be given by
:n_ \; = \mu u_t^a v_t^b + (1-\delta)n_t
For simplicity, many studies treat \,\delta\, as a fixed constant. But the fraction of workers separating per period of time can be determined endogenously if we assume that the value of being matched varies over time for each worker-firm pair (due, for example, to changes in productivity).

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Matching theory (economics)」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.